The
stage of monopoly capitalism (imperialism)
Throughout
the first phase of its existence, from the Industrial Revolution of the latter
half of the 18th century, to the end of the 19th century, the capitalist mode
of production was characterised by the existence of a large number of
independent firms in every sector of industry. None of these firms was able to
dominate any particular branch of production, and consequently the predominant
pattern of capitalist relations was what bourgeois theorists called free
competition, or laissez faire. Each firm sought to capture a larger fraction of
the market by reducing the selling price of its commodities. In this period,
the capitalist market was extended over the entire world through the export of
industrial consumer goods to areas of the globe where pre-capitalist relations
still prevailed (Asia, Africa, Latin America).
From the end of the 19th century, however, the period of free
competition gave way to a historically new stage of capitalism, characterised
by the monopolisation of separate branches of industry by one or a few large
firms.
This transition was facilitated by a technological revolution in
which the electric motor and the internal combustion engine supplanted the
steam engine as the principal sources of energy for industry and for
transportation. Entirely new industries developed (electricity, electrical
goods, oil, motor vehicles, chemical industries), and these required greater
initial capital outlays than the old industries. This radically reduced the
number of potential competitors.
This new historical period was a product of the operation of
capitalism's basic laws of motion. The concentration and centralisation of
capital led to the formation of powerful monopolistic associations (cartels,
syndicates, trusts) and to a new form of giant undertaking combining several
enterprises linked together by the banks. The so-called free competition of a
multitude of small capitalist firms gave way to the domination of national
markets by a handful of financial groups simultaneously controlling banks,
other financial institutions, big industrial and transport trusts, big retail
store chains, etc.
Capitalist monopolies do not eliminate capitalist competition. In
non-monopolised sectors of the capitalist economy, competition continues in the
traditional form of price cutting. In the monopolised sectors, however,
competition no longer normally takes the form of price cutting, except in
international markets in which the various national monopolists continue to
struggle against each other. In their traditional domestic markets, however,
competition takes the form of struggle between monopolies for reduction of
production costs.
By controlling markets and limiting price competition, the big
trusts obtain monopolistic superprofits — rates of profit superior to those of
companies in the non-monopolised sectors. Monopolies can control markets only
by limiting growth of production, and therefore accumulation of capital, within
them. On the other hand, these same monopolies are in possession of abundant
capital, accumulated due to monopolistic superprofits. Monopoly capitalism is
therefore characterised by the accumulation of surplus capital in the hands of
the monopolies of the industrialised capitalist countries. This surplus capital
must seek new fields for profitable investment. The export of capital from the
industrialised countries thus becomes an essential trait of the monopoly
capitalist era.
The export of capital to the non-industrialised areas of the world
(and the goods bought with this capital — mainly infrastructural facilities to
cheapen the export of raw materials from these areas) gave the capitalists of
the industrialised countries a major interest in establishing permanent control
over these areas. The rise of monopoly capitalism was therefore accompanied by
a feverish drive to assert direct political control over the non-industrialised
areas of the world by converting them into colonies of the major capitalist
powers. Thus the monopoly capitalist era is distinguished not merely by the
domination of each of the advanced capitalist countries by a small number of
monopolist firms and associations, but by the creation of a world imperialist
system based on the division of the globe into oppressor and oppressed nations.
The massive export of capital to the colonial and semi-colonial
countries (the so-called Third World) for the organisation of capitalist
production of raw materials, created and consolidated a specific mixture of
pre-capitalist and capitalist relations of production which prevented the
development of large-scale industry within these countries. Foreign capital's
domination over the accumulation of capital in the Third World stifled the
process of primitive accumulation of capital in the hands of the indigenous
capitalists. Thus, while imperialism integrated the colonial and semi-colonial
countries into the world capitalist market, it also consolidated a permanent
gap in average labour productivity between the industrialised capitalist countries
and the Third World.
The essential feature of imperialism is manipulation of the uneven
development of labour productivity in different sectors of the world capitalist
economy in order to extort monopoly superprofits.
The largest share of these superprofits is derived from the
imperialist countries themselves. Here, in the largest and most developed
capitalist markets, monopoly power (strict regulation of production, market
apportionment, monopoly pricing, favourable access to credit, control of
scientific research, export of capital and privileged connections with the
state) drastically shifts the distribution of surplus value to the advantage of
the largest corporations. But significant superprofits are also appropriated
from the colonial and semi-colonial countries through the purchase of labour
power at a price much lower than its value in the industrialised countries, and
through unequal exchange of goods on the world market: Goods produced in
conditions of higher labour productivity (principally industrial goods) are
exchanged for goods produced in conditions of lower labour productivity
(predominantly mineral and agricultural raw materials). As a result, the
capitalists of the imperialist countries are able to appropriate a large part
of the value produced in the Third World.
Monopoly capitalism not only intensifies all the classical
contradictions of capitalism, but also adds new ones:
- Imperialist
exploitation of the colonies and semi-colonies retards and distorts the
indigenous development of capitalism in these countries, perpetuating and
intensifying their economic backwardness and their dependent and
subordinate relationship to the advanced capitalist countries. It creates
a permanent division of the world into rich nations and poor nations, consigning
the majority of humanity to perpetual destitution.
- Monopoly
capitalism intensifies the contradiction involved in private appropriation
of the output of an effectively socialised process of production. The
functions of ownership and management are increasingly separated as the
richest section of the capitalist class becomes transformed into rentiers
(appropriating capital via large share holdings, state bonds, foreign
securities, interest on capital loans, etc.). The monopoly capitalist thus
appears as the purest type of capitalist, with appropriation of surplus
value no longer masked in any way by payment for a managerial task in the
productive process.
- Monopoly
superprofits, the condition for which is the relative limitation of
production, create the contradiction of overcapitalisation. This takes the
form of a mass of money capital unable to find profitable new fields of
productive investment, and chronic underuse of existing productive
capacity.
Monopoly
capitalism seriously restricts the prodigious development of the productive
forces that characterised the age of laissez-faire capitalism. With its
artificial restriction of production and sharing of markets between the big
corporations, monopoly capitalism becomes a fetter on the development of the productive
forces, leading to a general crisis that affects all aspects of capitalist
society — economic, political, cultural and moral.
This general crisis is most graphically manifested in the growing
inability of capitalism to contain the development of the productive forces
within the framework of private property, in a sharpening of social
contradictions both within and between nations, and in the growing tendency of
the productive forces to be transformed into forces of destruction that
threaten the maintenance of human civilisation, and increasingly, even the
survival of life on Earth.
Social Plugin